Donor Matching Funds Announced!

A generous donor has offered to match all contributions dollar-for-dollar for the next $10,000 raised, doubling the impact of your donation and helping us reach our fundraising goal faster.

$17,360 of $60,000 raised

On Tariffs and Trade (and Why Trade is Better for America)

by | Mar 5, 2018

On Tariffs and Trade (and Why Trade is Better for America)

by | Mar 5, 2018

Beautiful commerce | Pixabay

I have a huge trade imbalance with Wal-Mart.

Huge.

I spend hundreds of dollars on groceries and other items every month, but never–not once–has Wal-Mart ever bought something from me. Maybe I should stop shopping at Wal-Mart as a way of sticking it to them.

Or not.

I actually benefit a great deal from my trade imbalance with Wal-Mart. Generally speaking, my groceries are cheaper than at other stores where I could shop, and the wide selection of home, auto, electronic, and other valuables makes getting what I need easy, even when the contents of my list are diverse.

My trade imbalance with Wal-Mart makes me better off not in spite of the fact that they take my money, but because they take my money. I can’t eat dollar bills, after all, nor can I use them to keep me warm or maintain my car. Hoarding money (by, say, stuffing it under my mattress) does me no good. But the goods I can get by giving it to Wal-Mart can feed me, keep me warm, and ensure that my car runs as it should.

You–the reader–probably think it’s silly to think of my economic relationship with Wal-Mart as a trade imbalance, and you’d be right. Even if you’re among the one-in-three Americans that remains skeptical of international trade, you’d probably agree that it would be bizarre to think of trade between states–Idaho and California, for example–in terms of deficits and surpluses. (Which saves us from having to calculate the ratio of potato-to-computer chips, am I right?) But here’s an interesting principle hidden in our examples: borders are economically irrelevant to trade. Put differently, the same rules of economics apply equally to trade across international borders as to trade between individuals and across state borders.

Let’s go back to my trade imbalance with Wal-Mart: when I buy from Wal-Mart, I’m not losing by giving up my dollars in exchange for goods. If anything, I’m winning. After all, in a normal trade situation, each side has to feel as though they’re walking away better than when they started, or the trade won’t take place at all.

The same is true in international trade. As economist Mark J. Perry points out, it’s individuals and firms that engage in trade, not countries (in the abstract). Furthermore, argues Perry, in exchanging goods with foreign producers (China, for example), it is just as reasonable to think of Americans as having a “merchandise surplus” exactly equal to the number of dollars spent on Chinese goods, and of Chinese consumers as having a “merchandise deficit” equal to the (comparatively smaller) number of dollars spent on American goods. And why shouldn’t we think in those terms? After all, the poor in every country (including China and the United States) are able to buy, on average, 60% more merchandise because of international trade than they would otherwise be able to without it.

But what of the dollars that have now gone to China? I hinted at this in the previous paragraph: they come back to the United States in the form of foreign direct investment (FDI for short) by Chinese firms and the purchase of American goods by Chinese consumers. America may have a trade deficit (in terms of dollars leaving the country), but it also has a surplus in investment and lending. This is great news for Americans: the US International Trade Administration estimates that FDI from American trading partners supports about 12 million jobs in the United States.

Let’s say you’re unconvinced by arguments for free trade.  You, the keen Trade Skeptic, will, no doubt, object at this last figure. After all, you might argue, trade deals have resulted in the loss of American jobs. And that’s actually true.  Between 2000 and 2010, for instance, NAFTA (the North American Free Trade Agreement) resulted in the loss of 728,000 manufacturing jobs, thereby displacing American factory workers. This was no doubt an extremely stressful reality for those workers, but there are some things to keep in mind about this number:

  • because of trade with Mexico, factory wages in American jobs created by NAFTA are 15-20% higher than the wages in those quarter-million lost jobs
  • manufacturing output in the United States has increased 40% since the US entered NAFTA
  • during the period of 2000 to 2010, 5.6 million manufacturing jobs were lost in total, only 13% of which (those 700,000+ jobs I mentioned before) were due to international trade–fully 85% of those 5.6 million jobs were destroyed because of gains in productivity from technology
  • the resulting fall in consumer prices, rise in productivity, and increased range of goods available amount to a net gain of $450,000 to the American economy per job lostthat’s $327.6 billion (not exactly chump change)
  • and, lest we think of those jobs destroyed by NAFTA as a static loss to American workers, the United States economy creates and destroys somewhere in the neighborhood of 7 million jobs every quarter, or ten times the number of jobs destroyed by NAFTA over the course of a decade

“Objection,” you might respond. “Trade with our enemies represents a national security threat.”

Well… no. Taking steel production as an example, 70% of steel used in American manufacturing is American-made, and the vast majority used in national defense manufacturing is American steel. Besides, the four countries from which the United States imports steel the most are our allies. But even if this weren’t the case, economic interdependence between countries tends to act as a conflict deterrent–if your political enemies have huge investments in your economy, and vice versa, why would you bomb each other?

“Ah,” you say, “but international trade and globalization have led greedy American companies to send American jobs overseas in search of cheap labor.”

The reality is that 90% or more of jobs outsourced are meant to service foreign markets. International trade, after all, is the best means of opening up wider markets for American goods. In fact, the evidence shows that a 10% increase in American business investment in other countries is associated with a 2.2% increase in investment by American firms in the United States, and for every 10% rise in pay for foreign employees of American companies, American employees at home enjoy a 4.0% pay-raise. And this isn’t just true for Americans. Increasing the volume of trade leads to higher wages in general.

“What about making sure American companies are competitive in a global market?” you ask.

In our age of global markets, supply chains are widely distributed across nations. In fact, 43% of imports are production goods–goods that American firms use in the process of making consumer goods–and the costs of tariffs on imports are shared almost equally between the foreign producer and the domestic consumer; so tariffs aren’t just “taxes on other countries.” The real-world outcome of tariffs is to increase prices and decrease demand, making consumers poorer; that’s not awesome.

And historically, the nations that have been most competitive in trade have been those nations with the most liberal trade policies. In developing nations with freer trade, economic growth averaged 4.49% per year from 1970 to 1989, while developing nations with higher tariffs and more restrictive trade only grew 0.69% annually during that period. Among developed nations like the United States, the numbers were 2.29% and 0.74%, with the more open economies again growing at higher rates.

I could go on. I could mention that countries that adopted freer trade policies between 1950 and 1998 experienced higher growth and investment rates than they did pre-liberalization. I could write about the fact that older, more established firms (you know, the ones tariffs would likely serve best) are net job destroyers, while firms less than five years old are net job creators. I could riff on the false notion that high tariffs were the cause of high growth in the late 19th century. I could cite study after study that shows that freer trade leads to faster growth for every country involved. Heck, I could even make the argument that freer trade leads to happier populations.

But I think I’ve made my point. Trade is good. No, trade is amazing. Sure, it causes some reconfiguring of the American economy, but that has made us incredibly wealthy.

You, the Trade Skeptic, may remain unconvinced, and I’m comfortable with that notion. After all, it can take dozens of contacts with an idea before we become comfortable with it. But the evidence is clear, convincing, and overwhelming in support of free trade.

So, let’s not start a trade war with ourselves, yeah?

Matt Knight

Matt Knight

Matt Knight is an economics major at Utah State University and blogs at Ignore This.

View all posts

Our Books

libertarian inst books

Related Articles

Related

TGIF: Damn Consumers!

TGIF: Damn Consumers!

Global free trade is about individual, not national, freedom—for consumers and producers who import raw materials, tools, and semi-finished products. Aside from its role as an aspect of personal liberty, free trade's efficiency benefits have been well-established...

read more
You Don’t Want to Get Out of Line…

You Don’t Want to Get Out of Line…

The fallout from the failed assassination attempt on former President Donald Trump during a rally in Butler, Pennsylvania continues. Speculation abounds that it was an “inside job,” the head of the Secret Service became “embattled” and resigned, and the assassin’s...

read more
Black Magic, Mad Science, and Super-Nazis

Black Magic, Mad Science, and Super-Nazis

On a London soundstage in 1987, a British pop star is filming a music video when he is interrupted by a visitor who has what he considers an insane request: You’re asking me to help you because Nazis from another dimension are trying to take over the world and only...

read more

Restricting Production

"At the bottom of the interventionist argument there is always the idea that the government or the state is an entity outside and above the social process of production, that it owns something which is not derived from taxing its subjects, and that it can spend this...

read more
America’s Palace Coup

America’s Palace Coup

On Sunday, July 21 at around 1:30pm Eastern time someone with access to President Joe Biden’s social media accounts posted that he was dropping out of the presidential election. The announcement was not on any form of official stationary and the signature was...

read more

Pin It on Pinterest

Share This